UKIP-vs-EUkip

UKIP-vs-EUkip
UKIP-vs-EUkip CLICK The Pic. for travel!

Wednesday 1 December 2010

01-Dec-2010 - STANDPOINT Column by Tim CONGDON

01-Dec-2010 - STANDPOINT Column by Tim CONGDON
December issue of Standpoint

The last two months have been among the most interesting of my life. Like most people in this country, I have been horrified by the transfer of powers, or so-called “competences”, from our own Parliament to the institutions of the European Union. Since I joined the UK Independence Party in January 2007 a small group of members has encouraged me to try for the leadership, even though the leader from 2006 to 2009 and the party’s most well-known publicist – Nigel Farage MEP – has a strong following. When Lord Pearson stood down from the leadership in August, I “threw my hat into the ring”. In the end Farage secured three times as many votes as me and so is again leader, but I came second and my supporters are not too unhappy. When I started in late August, I was a 50-to-1 outsider.
I am about to make a confession which beforehand I would not have believed possible: I greatly enjoyed the hubbub and tension of competitive politics. I also learned a great deal about my country and its misgovernment. In particular, the experience brought home how important the insights of the Virginia School of Political Economy, or “the economics of politics”, are to modern political activity. Its leaders – James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock – did their main work in the 1960s and 1970s, but its relevance to understanding the European Union’s emasculation of our own parliamentary institutions is greater than ever.
Buchanan and Tullock’s central point was that the tools of economic analysis can be applied to topics such as politics, bureaucracy, law, constitutions and so on, as well as to economists’ more familiar concerns like the determination of prices and quantities of goods and services. When they were writing, an implicit assumption of most public debate was that the government existed to serve the public interest. By extension, the purpose of political action was Benthamite, to achieve the greatest good of the greatest number.
The Virginia School’s most devastating proposition was that the Benthamite assumption was invalid. Politicians are human beings, not the expressions of “the general will”, whatever that might be; they are greedy and imperfect, and have their own self-interested material aspirations. So in practice many government decisions are taken with a view to the aggrandizement – including the financial aggrandizement – of political cliques, the greatest good of oneself and one’s chums.
Of course politicians’ personal gain is not the only influence on government decisions, and the balance between the high-minded public interest and low-grade private interests varies over time and between nations.  The MPs’ expenses scandal in 2009 showed that in Britain the balance had moved dangerously in the wrong direction and confirmed the validity of Peter Oborne’s analysis in his 2007 minor classic, The Triumph of the Political Class.
Oborne’s indictment extended beyond Parliament. To quote, “the civil service, the political parties, the judiciary, the intelligence services and the media have all been captured or compromised”. But Oborne was curiously silent on the greatest of these scandals in our era, the capture and compromise of virtually the entire British political system by the EU bureaucracy. Today most of our legislation, under the alien labels of “directives” and “regulations”, emerges from the European Council of Ministers by a mysterious process that only a handful of people in this country understand.
In the Britain of 1960 millions of people flocked to the cinema to view with pride such films as The Dambusters and Sink the Bismarck. How can that same nation submit, 50 years later, to foreign control of its farming, fisheries, energy resources, financial regulation and external trade, as well to the undermining of legal protections (such as habeas corpus and trial by jury) which have been basic to its constitutional tradition for centuries?
The answer, in essence, is that the British political class has been bribed. Too many of its members have taken decisions for the greater good of themselves and their chums. The corruption at work is largely insidious and opaque, with two processes being particularly important. First, lazy and rather dim politicians have ceded powers to foreign bureaucrats for the sake of a soft life. The truth is that nowadays very few government ministers write their speeches, organize their diaries and set up their meetings. In effect, they are told what they can and cannot do by civil servants.
Not surprisingly, over time the national bureaucracies have become contemptuous of the people’s elected representatives. Civil servants see the organization of an international, pan-European bureaucracy under EU auspices as the means of transferring power to where it ought to belong, namely to themselves. Bureaucrats have the great advantage over the politicians that they are much cleverer and do not have to seek re-election, and in the EU they are undoubtedly winning the battle for control.
Secondly, the civil servants invent structures that encourage politicians to approve further integration. For example, the European Parliament now offers subsidies (ostensibly to pay for “research” and such like) to MEPs who form “pan-European groupings” and “pan-European parties”. So subsidies to promote European integration are now being offered to MEPs of separatist parties – including the UK Independence Party – who are supposed to be totally opposed to it.
If the Virginia School is right, these MEPs – meant to protect their country’s independence – might even accept the money that is being dangled in front of them.

Tuesday 30 November 2010

30-Nov-2010 - International Monetary Research - Tim CONGDON's News Letter

30-Nov-2010 - International Monetary Research - Tim CONGDON's News Letter


Weekly e-mail from Tim Congdon of International Monetary Research Ltd. – 30th November, 2010
Brief upturn in Eurozone M3 is fading
……………………
The first half of 2010 saw a potentially encouraging development in Eurozone money growth, with a return to growth – even if very slow growth – in M3. The resumption in money growth was most well-defined in Germany, where it owed much (in terms of the credit counterparts) to banks‟ purchases of government securities. On 22nd October I prepared a weekly e-mail noting the better numbers. I also expressed the hope that they foreshadowed a wider preparedness on the part of policy-makers to monetize budget deficits, in order to maintain money growth at a positive, although moderate, rate. (If banks are being forced to shrink risk assets – as is currently the case – some degree of deficit monetization is the only way to keep the quantity of money growing.)
The purpose of this e-mail is merely to update the story. It turns out that in the last two months Eurozone M3 has fallen slightly. The fall is not catastrophic, but my hopes of a sustained resumption of money growth have not been met. In last week‟s e-mail I was very critical of the ECB‟s current neglect of „the second pillar‟, i.e., the monetary analysis which in the Bundesbank tradition argued for low, stable growth of broad money. In fact, as far as I can see, the ECB‟s researchers are in such chaos over the various threats to the integrity of the Eurozone that they are indifferent to the stagnation of M3 since late 2008 and have no meaningful agenda to end it. The upward blip in M3 in the spring and summer of 2010 was an accident, not the result of deliberate policy. Eurozone leading indicator indices are fairly satisfactory at present, particularly for the core countries (Germany, France and so on), but early 2011 will see persisting macroeconomic agony in the peripheral PIGS nations (i.e., Portugal, Ireland, Greece and Spain). The Eurozone needs the deliberate creation of money by the state (i.e., “quantitative easing”), but that is not in prospect in the next few months. The Eurozone‟s strains will continue.
2
The latest Eurozone money trends
The ECB has just published the October M3 number. It was the second fall in a row, so that the three-month annualised rate of change is now down to almost nothing. The chart below asks, ‘as an upturn [in money growth] started?’. The answer is ‘no, not on a sustained basis’. (See the violet line in the chart below. In August Eurozone M3 jumped by 0.9% in the month, i.e., at an annualised 12%. This was heartening, but it seems in fact to have been a flash in the pan.)
With the banks in the peripheral PIGS countries still having immense difficulty in funding existing assets, and so under pressure to shrink balance sheets and liabilities, a resumption in the growth of bank balance sheets – and hence in M3 – for the Eurozone as a whole is heavily dependent on banking policy in the core countries. Attitudes in the ECB, the Bundesbank and so on are largely a matter of conjecture, but the signs are that policy-makers have no organized plan to boost Eurozone money growth. (There is an obvious contrast with the Bank of England, which introduced ‘quantitative easing’ in March 2009 deliberately to boost broad money, and – more debatably – the Federal Reserve, which has set about so-called ‘QE2’ in recent weeks.)
Since the PIGS countries cannot devalue, the easiest escape–route from their current macroeconomic agony would be a marked easing of monetary conditions in their main trading and financial partners, i.e., the other members of the Eurozone. But that does not appear to be in prospect. The early months of 2011 will see continued severe macroeconomic strains in the PIGS group, accompanied by worries about the break-up of the Eurozone.
-10-5051015% Crash in Eurozone money growth appears to be over: has an upturn started? Annual rate of change Three-month annualised rate of changeLatest value is October2010

Enhanced by Zemanta

Friday 26 November 2010

26-Nov-2010 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY RESEARCH News Letter



  
Weekly e-mail from Tim Congdon of International Monetary Research Ltd.  – 26th November, 2010

What of the ECB’s “second pillar” (i.e., money)?
……………………

In its early years the European Central Bank asserted – loudly and strongly – that it would follow a “stability-oriented” monetary policy. That phrase had been associated for over 30 years with the issuer of the deutschemark and the guardian of its value, the German Bundesbank. In particular, the ECB said it would adhere – like the Bundesbank – to a two-pillar approach to monetary policy-making. The first pillar was the analysis and forecasting of national income determination, the labour market and so on found in all central banks; the second pillar was more distinctive, with its centrepiece being “monetary analysis” to support a desired rate of money growth. The favoured money aggregate – like the Bundesbank’s – was generally the broad money measure, M3.

Much less is heard nowadays about the second pillar. In fact, the position of monetary analysis – let alone M3 targeting – in ECB policy-making has become unclear. In late 2008 and early 2009 the growth of Eurozone M3 collapsed, making a mockery of official claims that the ECB was pursuing a stability-oriented framework. However, the ECB’s latest Monthly Bulletin includes an article on ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’, which is not signed by its authors and so must be intended as a statement from the ECB itself. This weekly e-mail discusses the article in the context of recent Eurozone monetary developments. The main point is simple, that the ECB has participated in the international drive to make banks safe by means of a more restrictive set of Basle rules. It is engaged – like other central banks – in deterring the creation of money by the extension of bank credit to the private sector. In traditional monetary jurisdictions, like the USA or the UK, the state can replace the private sector and create new money balances by such methods as “quantitative easing”. But the article in the ECB’s November Monthly Bulletin says nothing whatever about QE or indeed about the importance of maintaining a positive rate of money growth to prevent deflation.


Eurozone money trends in the Great Financial Crisis  

Part of the ECB’s propaganda at its foundation was that it would pursue the same ‘stability-oriented’ framework as the German Bundesbank. Heavy emphasis was placed on the need for policy to be guided by a two-pillar approach. The first pillar consisted of a price level or inflation target where the forward views on price trends were based on “real forces”, such as analysis of the labour market and trends in aggregate demand. The second pillar, by contrast, focussed on money. According to Issing in his 2008 book on The Birth of the Euro,

At the press conference of 13 October 1998, when the President, Wim Duisenberg, presented the monetary policy strategy, a journalist asked about the ‘dual pillars’ for the strategy, namely the ‘monetary element’ and ‘the inflation forecast or real economy element’. Duisenberg pointed out that money would play a prominent role in the strategy of the ECB. Taking up the reference to ‘two pillars’, he emphasised that he could not say which of the two was the ‘stronger’ or ‘thicker’ one.

The initial statement of ECB strategy mentioned a ‘reference value’ for M3 broad money, although it did not include a specific target. Implicit in the ECB strategy were two understandings, that inflation was ultimately ‘a monetary phenomenon’ and that large fluctuations in money growth would engender macroeconomic instability.

For much of its life the ECB did indeed preside over fairly stable growth of Eurozone M3, and its reward was an even-keeled Eurozone economy and an impressive degree of price stability (or, at any rate, low-inflation stability). Otmar Issing, the ECB’s first chief economist, certainly paid attention to trends in money growth. However, since Issing retired in 2006, the ECB’s economics research has not had the same intellectual consistency. The closure of the wholesale money markets in summer 2007 caused some parts of the Eurozone banking system to have severe difficulties in funding their assets. Since the escalation of the Great Financial Crisis in October 2008, Eurozone M3 growth has suffered a dramatic plunge. Indeed, the yo-yoing of M3 changes since 2006 – in effect, since Issing’s retirement – makes a mockery of the ECB’s supposed commitment to a stability-oriented framework in which steady growth of money is a key desideratum.

At any rate, in mid-2007 – before the Great Financial Crisis hit seriously – the ECB’s Governing Council encouraged an intensification of the monetary research effort. An article on ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ in the November 2010 issue of the ECB’s Monthly Bulletin is one product of this extra work. The article reiterates the ECB’s concern about trends in money as such, noting ‘compelling empirical evidence showing that, at lower frequencies, i.e., over medium to longer-term horizons, inflation shows a robust positive association with monetary growth’. The ECB’s authors seem to be particularly pleased with recent work on the household sector’s money demand function, in which they say that the desire to hold money balances is heavily influenced by wealth, including housing wealth. They also bless such constructs as ‘dynamic general equilibrium models’ – or even ‘dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models’ – of the economy. In the articles’ words, ‘Structural general equilibrium models that incorporate an active role for money and credit offer a formal and disciplined approach to explaining the money-holding decisions of households and firms.’ Such models are described as being superior to partial equilibrium exercises, since they lend themselves to testing counterfactual propositions.




But is this all so much ‘blah-blah’? Economists were assembling highly mathematical DSGE models a decade or so ago, and these were useless in anticipating or diagnosing the Great Financial Crisis, and in offering policy prescriptions for it. The article is eclectic and woolly about a number of key issues. Like similar exercises from other central banks, the article

1.      cannot make up its mind about whether ‘money’ or ‘credit’ is the variable that matters to the determination of macroeconomic outcomes,
2.      denies that a ‘single model can be expected to provide a fully satisfactory explanation of monetary developments at all times’, and
3.      invokes a ‘suite’ of models to explain different aspects of a complex reality.

In truth, the ECB’s article gives its economists a range of excuses to find numerous, often inconsistent or even contradictory answers to the many questions that are likely to be thrown at them. They can duck the single, hard and definite answer that comes from genuine understanding.

The above chart shows the dramatic crash in money growth that occurred in late 2008 and early 2009, undoubtedly a major causal influence on the collapse in demand in 2009. But the ECB article on ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ nowhere presents a clear and exact account of the forces responsible for the money crash. In my view the omission has to be described as appalling. The article does have a review of so-called ‘shocks’ to M3 growth, but it mixes up demand factors (i.e., those that affect the demand to hold money balances) with supply factors (i.e., those which affect the rate at which banks expand their balance sheets), and – to this analyst at least – the result is cryptic, muddled and almost incomprehensible. (See the text in the box below, with its references to ‘money capital formation’.)

A quotation from the latest ECB Monthly Bulletin



Above is a quotation (p. 95) from the article ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ in the ECB’s November 2010 Monthly Bulletin, on the ‘shocks’ – and so presumably the disruptive causal influences – that affect money growth. The emphasis is on changes in banks’ ‘monetary capital formation’, i.e., on the change in their non-deposit, non-monetary liabilities. Am I alone in finding the paragraph almost incomprehensible? The statement ‘shocks perturbing “capital formation” have exerted the most significant downward impact on GDP growth, inflation and M3 growth’ does in fact imply that the late 2008 emphasis on increasing banks’ capital/asset ratios was deflationary, but did the ECB really mean to say that? Extra bank capital was meant to boost bank lending and exert an upward impact on GDP growth!

What caused the crash in Eurozone money growth?

Assume that the traditional concern, of the Bundesbank and the original ECB, about M3 growth is correct. Assume, in other words, that the crash in M3 growth in late 2008 and early 2009 was a basic causal influence on the Great Recession in Europe. Two questions then arise, ‘what force (or forces) was (or were) responsible for the money growth crash?’ and ‘what can and should the ECB now do to restore a sensible middle-of-the-road rate of money growth similar to that which applied from 1999 to 2006?’.



The central cause of the money growth crash in the Eurozone – as elsewhere – was that banks stopped expanding their claims on the private sector. This is obvious from the chart, which shows bank lending to the private sector increasing by a mere 200b. euros in the year to September 2009 compared to about 1200b. euros in the year to September 2008. The sudden collapse in bank credit to the private sector had two main causes. First, in the middle of 2007 the international wholesale money market closed, so that banks heavily reliant on inter-bank funding (such as those in Greece, Ireland, etc.) could no longer readily expand their assets and somewhere else in the international banking system that meant slower growth of deposit liabilities (i.e., money). Secondly, in a grotesque misunderstanding of what was required for the purpose of macroeconomic stability, regulators decided in autumn 2008 to force banks quickly to raise capital/asset ratios. Subsequent efforts to boost capital/asset ratios had the effect of intensifying the money slowdown. Not surprisingly, the shedding of risk assets increased, not decreased. Meanwhile the raising of capital reduced the private sector’s deposit claims on the banks. (When I use my bank deposit to buy newly-issued bank shares, my bank deposit – and hence the quantity of money – falls.)

Banks’ capital-raising in 2009 was therefore a second force behind the money crash. ECB data show that banks’ longer-term liabilities (i.e., their equity and bond liabilities, mostly, or – in other words – their ‘monetary capital’) climbed by about 450b. euros in the year to December 2009, or by almost 7 ½% at a time when money and credit growth were virtually nothing. But in fact banks had been growing their longer-term liabilities by more than 5% a year for most of the previous decade.

Contrary to the (extraordinarily hard and frankly weird) paragraph in the ECB’s ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ article, the change in ‘monetary capital formation’ was not a particularly salient causal influence on the 2009 money crash. What differentiated 2009 from earlier years was the collapse in bank lending to the private sector. That was the cause of the slump in Eurozone money growth. The ECB participated in the wider scramble among central bankers and regulators to raise bank capital/asset ratios, and to that extent its activities contributed to the money crash and caused the Great Recession.


And what must now be done to raise Eurozone money growth?

The accusation in the last paragraph – that the ECB contributed to the Great Recession because of its endorsement of the move to higher bank capital/asset ratios – may seem harsh. After all, all the leading central banks endorsed the move to higher capital/asset ratios in the commercial banking industry. (And more fool them.) But there is an important difference between the ECB and the other central banks.

Commercial banks have two main kinds of assets and two main kinds of liability. The two main kinds of asset are claims on the private sector and claims on the state (i.e., claims on the government and/or the central bank, with claims on the central bank usually taking the form of cash); the two main kinds of liability are deposits, which are money, and non-deposit liabilities, such as equities and bonds, which are not money. Suppose that the task is to raise money growth (and so to defeat a recession), even though an overriding external factor (the idiocy of regulators, central banks, politicians, etc.) is preventing the expansion of banks’ claims on the private sector. It is then obvious that the only variable on which policy can work – taking official idiocy on banks’ capital as a given – is the banking system’s claims on the state.

Terrible mistakes have been made in monetary and banking policy in the last few years. Nevertheless, the key central banks in the English-speaking world – the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England – have now come to understand that, in collaboration with the government, they can alter the size of the banking system’s claims on the state. As I have explained on numerous occasions (but see, particularly in the recent past, my paper on ‘Monetary policy at the zero bound’ in the first 2010 issue of World Economics), two main approaches are available,

i.         direct borrowing by the government from the commercial banks, or
ii.       central bank purchases of assets from non-banks financed by the central bank issuing new cash reserves.

My general preference is for the first of these, because it is simple, and consequently avoids overblown and needlessly controversial central bank balance sheets. However, at present the enthusiasm for central bank independence has resulted in these decisions being regarded as the province of monetary policy-making and hence of central banks. In March 2009 the Bank of England embarked on large-scale purchases of government bonds and prevented a contraction in bank deposits, in a set of operations known as ‘quantitative easing’. The Federal Reserve had at that stage been involved in massive purchases of commercial paper from non-banks, later to be replace by massive purchases of mortgage-back paper. The effects of these operations on the level of bank deposits was the same as the Bank’s gilt purchases, but the chairman of the Federal Reserve – Ben Bernanke – favoured the term “credit easing”. At any rate, earlier this month the Fed announced operations very similar in character to the Bank’s March 2009 exercise, with $600b. of purchases of longs intended to increase the quantity of money.


The case for QE2 in the Eurozone

If the ECB’s economists seriously wanted to ‘enhance’ their ‘monetary analysis’, their focus today should be designing similar operations in the Eurozone. Yes, the Maastricht Treaty prevents governments from borrowing directly on overdraft terms from the European System of Central Banks. But

1.      The ECB and its member central banks can purchase government bonds in the secondary market, with two possible strategies,
i.                     They can do so in such blatant fashion that governments are, in effect, receiving direct central bank finance. The ECB’s purchases of Greek, Irish and Portuguese government debt in 2010 show that this option is available. (I should emphasize that I strongly oppose this sort of thing in general terms, but it is there in the extreme.)
ii.                   They can agree large targeted amounts of German bund purchases, French government bond purchases, etc., with the explicit objective of boosting both broad money and banks’ cash reserves, with the proportions between the various governments’ debt stocks agreed between finance ministers. The resulting operations would amount to multi-national, pan-European QE.
2.      Since the Maastricht Treaty does not prohibit commercial banks from holding government debt, the various governments of the Eurozone can arrange for their deficits to be financed mostly from the banks. They merely have to order their Debt Management Offices – if they have such institutions – to downplay their enthusiasm for the lowest cost form of finance and instead to ensure that, as far as possible, finance is from banks rather than non-banks. This instruction would of course not be permanent, but would be in force for as long as necessary to maintain a reasonable rate of growth of broad money. The size of the purchases would
i.                     need to be calibrated so that broad money growth was neither too fast nor too slow, and
ii.                   again, proportions between the various governments’ debt stocks would have to be agreed between finance ministers.

The challenge – in other words – is to design a set of “debt market operations” (using my vocabulary in the World Economics paper) to deliver positive and stable growth of M3. The challenge is particularly difficult in political and logistical term, because the Eurozone – unlike the USA or the UK – is not a traditional monetary jurisdiction, with one government, one central bank and one currency. Nevertheless, something could be organized. This the task to which the ECB’s economists and senior staff should now be addressing their attention.

The Club Med/PIGS group of countries are trapped in a downward deflationary spiral, where efforts to improve public finances aggravate monetary contraction, asset price declines, commercial bank insolvency and so on. The banking problems could be relieved only by a return to asset price inflation in the Eurozone as a whole, some of which would filter into the Club Med/PIGS countries. If the votaries of orthodoxy insist than any kind of asset price inflation is verboten, the answer is twofold. First, asset prices have been going up and down for centuries, and to insist that only downward movements are respectable is monetary sado-masochism. Secondly, moderate but positive money growth ought to be associated with mild asset price inflation. All being well, that would help Ireland, Greece, etc., without sparking rapid inflation in goods and labour markets.


Conclusion: the ECB has no active strategy to boost M3 growth

The article on ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ was badly-written and confusing. It gave little confidence that the ECB’s senior staff is now focussed on vital practical topics arising from the Great Recession. Most worrying of all, the ECB’s attitude towards ‘the second pillar’ – the distinctive emphasis on broad money growth for which the Bundesbank was once so celebrated – is now uncertain. The analyst has to wonder whether the ECB now has any organized view on money growth at all. Readers of the ‘Enhancing monetary analysis’ article in the November 2010 Monthly Bulletin certainly cannot find any guidance on the relative desirability of, say, 1% and 6% growth of M3 over the next twelve months.

But Europe’s macro outlook turns on whether M3 growth in 2011 is 1% rather than 6%. It is possible that – with no further prodding from policy-makers – Eurozone M3 growth next year will revive to 6%. But this seems implausible in view of the still worsening situation in the PIGS group. Particularly alarming were statements in press reports on the Irish situation that the rescue package will ensure that the Irish banks sell off a high proportion of their assets. Do any of the relevant officials understand that – when a bank sells an asset to a non-bank (say, an insurance company or a pension fund) – the effect on the quantity of money is the same as the repayment of a bank loan? Sure, the Irish banks have lost shareholders’ money and do not have enough capital to justify the present scale of their loan portfolios. But – unless offsetting steps are actively taken (by, for example, QE-type operations) – banks’ sales of loans to non-banks destroy money balances and add to the deflationary spiral. Two leading investment managers at Jupiter Asset Management – Guy De Blonay and Philip Gibbs – have today called for a QE2 programme to be unleashed by the ECB. They claim – very understandably – that Eurozone banks in general are too risky for their funds while the macroeconomic context is so disheartening. The analysis in this note supports the De Blonay-Gibbs position, although it must be recognised that QE is more difficult to structure in the Eurozone than in a traditional monetary jurisdiction. The alarming message from its November 2011 Monthly Bulletin is that the ECB has not begun to think about an agenda to restore positive money growth to the Eurozone.


26th November, 2010 

Thursday 28 October 2010

Notes on the huge downside to UKIP joining a pan EUropean party 28-Oct-2010

Notes on the huge downside to UKIP joining a pan EUropean party 28-Oct-2010

On the day Cameron returns from Brussels having agreed to a de facto EU Treasury crying triumph I have saved the UK £400mn although we still have to pay an extra £400 mn I reproduce below Tim Congdon's notes on UKIP's similar triumph bought by Bloom for a similar huge strategic give away.

Bloom and his boss Farage are quite happy to sell our birthright for a mess of pottage as it says in the Bible!


The funding of pan-European political parties

The following notes have been sent to me by Mr. Richard Teather, senior lecturer in tax law at Bournemouth University, to whom I am most grateful.



1) Pan-European political parties (or “Europarties”) are meant to be funded "from the general budget of the European Union", although funds are actually administered by the European Parliament.

2) Europarties are alliances of national political parties.  Although theoretically individuals could join a Europarty directly, they generally do not.

3) Europarties overlap with, but are different from, the "groups" within the European Parliament. (Thus, before 1999 the Conservative Party was not a member of the European People's Party as a Europarty, but it was a member of the EPP Group within the European Parliament.)

4) The party must meet various conditions to be approved as a “Europarty”, the main ones being:
  a) it must have political representation (at MEP, MP or regional assembly level) in at least a quarter of EU Member States [i.e., in seven states];
  b) it must "observe, in particular in its programme and in its activities, the principles on which the European Union is founded, namely the principles of liberty, democracy, respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms, and the rule of law"; and
  c) it must "have participated in elections to the European Parliament, or have expressed the intention to do so".

5) Funding of 10.6 million euros per year* is available and to be shared between all the recognised Europarties.  Some funding (1.6 million euros) goes equally to each recognised Europarty, but the remaining 9 million euros is divided up according to the number of MEPs each Europarty has.  It is therefore very valuable for a Europarty to have MEP members. At a rough calculation, each MEP member must be worth almost 15,000 euros p.a. to the Europarty. (* The number relates to 2008 and is probably much higher in 2011.)

6) Restrictions are imposed on what a Europarty can do with its funds. In particular funds can only be used for pan-European campaigns, not for "direct or indirect funding of national political parties or candidates", and funds cannot be used "to finance referenda campaigns". 

7) Additional funding of 5 million euros (again, the figure relates to 2008) for European “foundations” where “foundations” are think-tanks linked to each Europarty.

8) A Europarty based on the current EFD group (which has 32 members) would get funding of almost 600,000 euros p.a. plus funding of around 250,000 euros for an associated "foundation". 


These notes make sense given what I have heard elsewhere about the funding of pan-European political parties, but raise further questions. In fact, the whole subject is puzzling.

On the face of it, the EFD group would pick up a little under one million euros a year if all its constituent parties – including the UK Independence Party – decided to form a Europarty. 
Frankly, this is chickenfeed relative to
i.         the larger issues raised by the UK’s membership of the European Union and
ii.       the sums of money routinely discussed in British political fund-raising.
I am astonished that anyone involved in the leadership of UKIP could want to convert the party into a Europarty for such a trivial amount.

True enough, the basis of allocation between the notional Europarties is such as to encourage “groups” to convert themselves into “Europarties”. The European Union imposes a limit on the total that can be spent on Europarties. In other words, the trough has only a finite amount of swill inside it. If one group in the European Parliament does not convert itself into a Europarty (such as the proposed “European Alliance”), the amount of swill available for the other groups (i.e., those which do convert themselves) is higher than would otherwise be the case. Hence, the two sentences in the Bonici e-mail, “The European Alliance will help parties dissiminate [sic – she meant ‘disseminate’] information by using European funds available to us, and if we don't apply the other Parties/Alliances such as the PES, EPP, Greens etc... will have the money which is allocated to us to share between them. Basically it is like giving ammunition to your enemy for free.”

Nevertheless, it remains unclear to me what advantage UKIP would get from belonging to a Europarty such as the proposed “European Alliance”. The 600,000 euros (plus or minus 250,000 euros) could not be used for a specifically British political purpose in this country, but must instead be part of a pan-European political programme of some sort. Since the UK Independence Party is the only significant political force in the European Parliament committed to its nation’s withdrawal from the EU, how could such a pan-European political programme be to UKIP’s benefit?

Interestingly, Europarty money cannot be used for the purposes of promoting referendums. Indeed, this seems to be specifically identified as an unacceptable destination of Europarty money. 
There is an obvious - indeed hilarious – discrepancy between item 6 in Richard Teather’s notes above, and item 4, with its assertion that the EU “is founded” on “the principles of liberty, democracy, respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms, and the rule of law". Democracy? Oh, yes, the EU is founded on the principle of democracy, until Europe’s peoples vote against further European integration. When any of Europe’s peoples vote that way, the EU and its related “political class” ignores their democratic verdicts. Remember how the EU’s politicians and bureaucrats overrode referendum results in Ireland, France, the Netherlands, etc.

Since any money arising from Europarty status cannot be used to promote UKIP in the UK, I cannot see any purpose in seeking Europarty status. My view is that UKIP should have nothing to do with Europarties.


28th October, 2010

PAN EU POLITICAL PARTIES by Tim CONGDON 28-Oct-2010

Dear friends and supporters,

Two supporters have sent me further information about pan-European political parties (or, inevitably, "Europarties"). I am very grateful to

i. Lawrence Webb for some material on the history of the thinking - the highly integrationist thinking - behnd these parties and

ii. Richard Teather for information on the sums of money involved in their funding.
(Lawrence Webb is UKIP's London Region Organizer and Richard Teather is Senior Lecturer in Tax Law at Bournemouth University.) I have brought their material together in another note, again attached here.

In essence, UKIP in the UK would gain next to nothing from its MEPs converting their current "Europe for Freedom and Democracy" group into one constituent of a  larger pan-European party. Some money would become available to the new "Europarty", but only for the purpose of pan-European political activity. None of it could be used in the UK. In fact, the relevant EU regulation specifically says that the money must not be directed to fund the collecting of signatures in a referendum on, for example, continued EU membership.

In any case, the amount of money involved is trivial relative to the sums routinely mentioned in British political fund-raising. Does the future of UKIP really depend on one million euros handed to its MEP group, with numerous strings attached, by the European Parliament?

Of course I agree with the 2010 Torquay conference motion, that any decision on UKIP involvement with a pan-European political party (and/or foundation) must be put to the party membership as a whole. In any debate on the subject I will be emphatically opposed to UKIP having an association or involvement of any kind with a newly-formed pan-European political party.


Quote 
More on pan-European parties:

Threat or opportunity for the UK Independence Party?
Would the UK Independence Party betray its principles by joining a pan-European party of any kind, including a pan-European party which is (actually or allegedly) “Eurosceptic” in attitude? Or would UKIP benefit from extra funding made available – via the European Parliament – from the European Union?
In this note I discuss the origins of the idea of a pan-European party and the nature of the funding that would be opened up if UKIP were to join it.

Origins of the idea of pan-European parties

The first mention of pan-European parties was in 1992 in the Maastricht Treaty (section 41, added article 138a to the treaty of Rome). In its words, “Political parties at European level are important as a factor for integration within the Union. They contribute to forming a European awareness and to expressing the political will of the citizens of the Union." But – at that stage – political activity and party formations remained almost wholly national, and there was no suggestion that the European Union might fund political parties.

This changed in the 1997 Amsterdam Treaty, with article 138/191 envisaging a possible new mechanism to fund pan-European parties from the European Union‟s general budget. More explicitly, the 2001 Nice Treaty added a second paragraph to the Treaty of Rome. To quote, "The Council, acting in accordance with the procedure referred to in Article 251, shall lay down the regulations governing political parties at European level and in particular the rules regarding their funding." By implication, the European Parliament would become involved, and pan-European party funding would be regulated by the Council of Ministers and the European Parliament, acting together.

In 2003 Regulation (EC) No 2004/2003 (4 November 2003) defined what a "political party at European level" actually was. It also specified that EU funding should not go to national parties (as distinct from the new pan-European parties), either directly or indirectly. Further tweaking of the rules and regulations followed. The latest is Regulation (EC) No 1524/2007 (18 December 2007). The regulation both sets further limits on the activities that EU political funding may legitimately cover and paves the way for the financing of “political foundations” at the “European level".

The practical meaning of the regulation is that pan-European parties can set up and use EU money to meet the expenses of legally separate, but still affiliated “think-tanks”, while the funding of national parties as such remains forbidden. The revised regulation also contains wording which appears to gives pan-European parties the exclusive responsibility to campaign for the European elections. The precise message here is rather unclear and highly controversial, since – at face value – the EU appears to be trying to prevent a national party, such as the UK Independence Party, from participating in European elections. This is a grotesque insult to democracy and mocks the highfalutin verbiage in various EU founding documents.

The funding of pan-European political parties

The following notes have been sent to me by Mr. Richard Teather, senior lecturer in tax law at Bournemouth University, to whom I am most grateful.

1) Pan-European political parties (or “Europarties”) are meant to be funded "from the general budget of the European Union", although funds are actually administered by the European Parliament.

2) Europarties are alliances of national political parties. Although theoretically individuals could join a Europarty directly, they generally do not.

3) Europarties overlap with, but are different from, the "groups" within the European Parliament. (Thus, before 1999 the Conservative Party was not a member of the European People's Party as a Europarty, but it was a member of the EPP Group within the European Parliament.)

4) The party must meet various conditions to be approved as a “Europarty”, the main ones being:

a) it must have political representation (at MEP, MP or regional assembly level) in at least a quarter of EU Member States [i.e., in seven states];

b) it must "observe, in particular in its programme and in its activities, the principles on which the European Union is founded, namely the principles of liberty, democracy, respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms, and the rule of law"; and

c) it must "have participated in elections to the European Parliament, or have expressed the intention to do so".

5) Funding of 10.6 million euros per year* is available and to be shared between all the recognised Europarties. Some funding (1.6 million euros) goes equally to each recognised Europarty, but the remaining 9 million euros is divided up according to the number of MEPs each Europarty has. It is therefore very valuable for a Europarty to have MEP members. At a rough calculation, each MEP member must be worth almost 15,000 euros p.a. to the Europarty. (* The number relates to 2008 and is probably much higher in 2011.)

6) Restrictions are imposed on what a Europarty can do with its funds. In particular funds can only be used for pan-European campaigns, not for "direct or indirect funding of national political parties or candidates", and funds cannot be used "to finance referenda campaigns".

7) Additional funding of 5 million euros (again, the figure relates to 2008) for European “foundations” where “foundations” are think-tanks linked to each Europarty. Cool A Europarty based on the current EFD group (which has 32 members) would get funding of almost 600,000 euros p.a. plus funding of around 250,000 euros for an associated "foundation".

These notes make sense given what I have heard elsewhere about the funding of pan-European political parties, but raise further questions. In fact, the whole subject is puzzling.

On the face of it, the EFD group would pick up a little under one million euros a year if all its constituent parties – including the UK Independence Party – decided to form a Europarty. Frankly, this is chickenfeed relative to
i. the larger issues raised by the UK‟s membership of the European Union and
ii. the sums of money routinely discussed in British political fund-raising.

I am astonished that anyone involved in the leadership of UKIP could want to convert the party into a Europarty for such a trivial amount.

True enough, the basis of allocation between the notional Europarties is such as to encourage “groups” to convert themselves into “Europarties”. The European Union imposes a limit on the total that can be spent on Europarties. In other words, the trough has only a finite amount of swill inside it. If one group in the European Parliament does not convert itself into a Europarty (such as the proposed “European Alliance”), the amount of swill available for the other groups (i.e., those which do convert themselves) is higher than would otherwise be the case. Hence, the two sentences in the Bonici e-mail (which I sent out yesterday), “The European Alliance will help parties dissiminate [sic – she meant „disseminate‟] information by using European funds available to us, and if we don't apply the other Parties/Alliances such as the PES, EPP, Greens etc... will have the money which is allocated to us to share between them. Basically it is like giving ammunition to your enemy for free.”

Nevertheless, it remains unclear to me what advantage UKIP would get from belonging to a Europarty such as the proposed “European Alliance”. The 600,000 euros (plus or minus 250,000 euros) could not be used for a specifically British political purpose in this country, but must instead be part of a pan-European political programme of some sort. Since the UK Independence Party is the only significant political force in the European Parliament committed to its nation’s withdrawal from the EU, how could such a pan-European political programme be to UKIP’s benefit?
Interestingly, Europarty money cannot be used for the purposes of promoting referendums. Indeed, this seems to be specifically identified as an unacceptable destination of Europarty money. There is an obvious - indeed hilarious – discrepancy between item 6 in Richard Teather‟s notes above, and item 4, with its assertion that the EU “is founded” on “the principles of liberty, democracy, respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms, and the rule of law". Democracy? Oh, yes, the EU is founded on the principle of democracy, until Europe’s peoples vote against further European integration. When any of Europe’s peoples vote that way, the EU and its related “political class” ignores their democratic verdicts. Remember how the EU’s politicians and bureaucrats overrode referendum results in Ireland, France, the Netherlands, etc.

Since any money arising from Europarty status cannot be used to promote UKIP in the UK, I cannot see any purpose in seeking Europarty status. My view is that UKIP should have nothing to do with Europarties.

Tim Congdon
28th October, 2010

Wednesday 27 October 2010

Tim CONGDON'S TAKE ON APPARENT BETRAYAL OF UKIP BY MEPS 27-Oct-2010

Tim CONGDON'S TAKE ON APPARENT BETRAYAL OF UKIP BY MEPS 27-Oct-2010

From: TIMOTHY CONGDON <timcongdon@btinternet.com>
Date: 27 October 2010 20:26:01 CEST
To: undisclosed recipients: ;
Subject: Tim Congdon on the UK Independence Party and its possible involvement in a pan-European political party
 
E-mail sent to supporters of Tim Congdon’s bid for the leadership of the UK Independence Party, on 27th October 2010
This e-mail is sent to you because I have been informed - or have good reason to believe - that you are a supporter of my bid to become leader of UKIP. If you do not want to receive e-mails from me, perhaps you would let me know. The leadership campaign rules are intended to encourage discussion and debate, but also to prevent spamming.      
 ................................
Dear friends and supporters,
Since the 1950s the project of European integration has been driven by unelected bureaucrats, with the political leaderships (including some elected politicians) acting as figureheads and accomplices. The bureaucrats (I am thinking in particular of the secretariat of the European Commission) are very clever. They have found ways to bribe, often in rather subtle ways, any politicians that get in their way. Several members of Britain's Labour Party were opposed to the Common Market in the 1970s and early 1980s, but today luxuriate in the joys of a European Union position (of one kind or another).
Could even the UK Independence Party be bribed in this way? Of course not, you might say. Well, unfortunately it's a little more complicated. The last few weeks have seen rumours that a new pan-European political party would be formed, with the UK Independence Party (or at any rate UKIP MEPs) being invited to join. I have been hoping that these rumours were untrue. But an e-mail has been sent to UKIP MEPs by a lady called Sharon Bonici and, if I have read it correctly, it is a clear-cut invitation to participate in the development of a pan-European political party. I understand that it has been sent to UKIP MEPs. Indeed, the e-mail says that Mr. Godfrey Bloom has "confirmed" that he does wish to participate in the new pan-European political party, to be known as "the European Alliance". (The Bonici e-mail - with some prefatory notes by me - is attached, in both Word and PDF formats.)  
I stand open to correction (and would in fact like to be wrong), but my interpretation of the Bonici e-mail is that extra money will be made available to the MEPs of national parties - not necessarily to their salaries, of course - who decide to belong to the European Alliance. Perhaps Ms. Bonici - to whom I suppose this e-mail will be forwarded - might like to repudiate that suggestion, if it is untrue.
For myself, I would like to reiterate what I have said throughout the 2010 election campaign for the leadership of the UK Independence Party, that
1. I do not want to be a MEP,
2. I intend to finance from my own resources (up to £100,000 a year) a London-based office which is to concentrate on the organization of UKIP political campaigning in the UK, and
3. The centre of gravity of the UK Independence Party must be in the UK.
At the Torquay party conference in September I supported the motion, proposed by Steph McWilliam, that the party membership must be consuulted on the question of UKIP's involvement in a pan-European political party. As is well-known in party circles, Nigel Farage opposed the motion. The motion was in fact carried overwhelmingly. In my view, the party membership must be consulted on a possible development of this kind, which is basic to the purpose and definition of the UK Independence Party, and even in fact to its very name.
Gerard Batten MEP has sent me an e-mail to say that he will respect and abide by the Torquay conference motion.
I hope that all three other candidates in the current leadership election will confirm that they will abide by the Torquay conference vote on this subject and, more generally, will respect the principle of party democracy.
........................................
Memo on an e-mail from Sharon Bonici to interested individuals (including UKIP MEPs) about a new pan-European party, to be called “the European Alliance
I have highlighted key passages of the e-mail in red.
Note that the e-mail refers to:
1.      The proposed new party, to be called “the European Alliance”, without clarifying whether – for example – existing Eurosceptic parties, such as the UK Independence Party, are to keep their present names in future elections.
2.      The alleged urgency of making a decision about participation in such a pan-European party. (To whom and what are the “paper work” to be handed in? The question is basic.)
3.      “European funds” being made “available to us”. (From whom are such funds coming? The European Parliament? Assume that the funds come from the European Parliament. Then – in the event that UKIP MEPs were to participate in “the European Alliance” – their activities would be funded by the European Parliament, an institution avowedly central to the project of European integration.)
4.      The possibility of the “consent” of party members, the meaning of which is (to me at least) unclear, but may intended as a fig-leaf to pacify those UKIP members who at the 2010 Torquay party conference voted overwhelmingly that the issue of pan-European parties must be decided by the party membership.
5.      Godfrey Bloom, as already confirming his wish to participate in the European Alliance project. (Mr. Bloom is said to be “EFD”, not “UKIP”. EFD stands, of course, for “Europe of Freedom and Democracy”, the existing pan-European grouping to which a majority of UKIP MEPs are attached.)
6.      A closing line, in which the European Parliament is acknowledged as having the power “to approve the new Alliance”. This is – almost certainly – the power to approve the Alliance, meaning the power to approve the Alliance in order to establish the Alliance’s eligibility for various monies from the European Parliament because it meets certain criteria of pan-European-ness.   
(These notes prepared by Tim Congdon on 27th October, 2010.)
From: European Alliance For Freedom [mailto:europeanallianceforfreedom@gmail.com]
Sent:
26 October 2010 12:57
To: xxxxxxx
Subject: European Alliance For Freedom
Dear xxxxxxxxxxx,

 We are currently setting up
a new European Alliance and most members I spoke to who are joining or joined would really like to see you on board. I would like to set up a meeting with you to discuss and hope to get your interest in being part of this new poject. I will be in parliament today Tuesday, Wednesday and Thursday this week and would appreciate if we can meet up at your convenience. We need to hand in all the paper work and signautres by the end of the week, so this is a bit urgent.

The
Alliance will serve to build campaigns across Europe to promote various causes; For example one of the first campaings we can engage ourselves in is to generate 1 million signatures to be able to instigate a pan wide European referendum on Turkey. The idea is to use the million signature clause according to the Lisbon Treaty.

We can build a multilingual website for people to sign up and advertise it in every member state. This will automatically gives us a huge database of Eurosceptics and people across
Europe with the same ideology. In time we need to campaign again on another issue we can engage these people on various campaigns and keep the Commission on their toes.

We will print research publication in various languages.

The Alliance will help parties dissiminate information by using European funds available to us, and if we don't apply the other Parties/Alliances such as the PES, EPP, Greens etc... will have the money which is allocated to us to share between them. Basically it is like giving ammunition to your enemy for free.

The
Alliance can finance various campaigns in your country if you are members with billboards, TV adverts,newspaper adverts,leaflets etc...or any other campaigns you decide you want to do in your country.

The Alliance will not get involved politically in any country without the consent of its members.

You can join as a Party or as individual members of the European Parliament. We would like to have you as our Danish representitives on board and our aim is to have representation in every European country including those that are not EU members such as
Iceland, Norway and Switzerland. We also hope that in the next European Elections we can become a strong voice in the European Parliament in 2014

So far we have the following confirmed -

1.Godfrey Bloom MEP - UK (UK- EFD)

2.Sweden Democrats - Sweden 20 MP's in the national parliament

3.BIW - Germany - 1 member in the regional parliament

4.Frank Van Hecke MEP- Belgium
   Philip Claeys MEP

5. Paksas Rolandas MEP (EFD)
    Imbraras Juozas MEP
 
 Still to confirm or be confirmed -

6. PVV - Nederlands

7.Provero Fiorello MEP - (Italy -EFD)
8.Paska Jaroslav  MEP- (Slovakia -EFD)

9.Fiorello Provera MEP -(Italy -EFD)
We do have other parties and members who are interested but at the moment we would like to take it step by step until we apply and everything is set with like minded people.

I thank you for your time and attention, should you wish for more info do not hesitiate to contact me by email or on
Mobile: xxxxxxxxxx.

Hope to receive a positive reply and to have you on board this new venture.

Attached please find a copy of the statute and an application form. For the moment everything is provisional and subject to change in the first congress
if we are approved by parliament as a new Alliance.

Best Regards,
Sharon Ellul Bonici

You are not only free to circulate this message more widely to other party members. You are positively requested to circulate it widely to as many party members as possible.
 
With best wishes                      
 Tim Congdon
Enhanced by Zemanta